After Joshua Cooper Ramo published his conception of the “Beijing Consensus” in 2004, a heated debate about its applicability for developing economies ensued. The Beijing Consensus contrasted the Chinese model of development with the US-centric “Washington Consensus.” Rather than emphasizing the neo-liberal mantra of unfettered market forces paired with deregulation, privatization, and minimalist government, the China model pursued, according to Ramos, an approach that is flexible and “does not believe in uniform solutions for every situation.”
However, the Beijing Consensus rapidly came to denote an authoritarian form of state-led development. The debate about its applicability generally resulted in the view that this new Consensus was not gaining international traction. Even most Chinese observers concluded that China's development experiences and national conditions were too unique as to be fully applied abroad.
In the past couple of years this view has become less prominent. The US-centric Washington Consensus, already deeply impaired by the jarring experiences of the 2008 Global Financial Crisis, is being challenged by a new emergent “China model.” This is not an earth-shattering move to a new development doctrine, but rather a gradual shift to a more eclectic view of what works and what not.
The emergence of a new China model builds in part on Ramos' original conception. It emphasizes unconventional approaches to economic policy, including a combination of mixed ownership, basic property rights, and heavy government intervention. But most importantly, it consists of a new conception of how to face developmental challenges, contrasting substantially with the Washington Consensus.
To be clear, proponents of the Washington Consensus all along failed to appreciate the diverse nature of developing economies. Countries facing developmental challenges invariably pick and choose certain aspects of a policy package, combining it with unique national factors and the developmental experiences of other, often more successful neighboring economies. Unsurprisingly, economies that closely followed the one-size-fits-all package of the Washington Consensus have not faired too well. Mexico serves as a poster child of attempting to follow many of its policy prescriptions, but still underperforming.
The emergent China model actually builds on several aspects of the Washington Consensus, but is by far less dogmatic. Fiscal and monetary prudence, an emphasis on private initiative and entrepreneurship, and the government's role in establishing good soft and hard infrastructures for economies to thrive are basic commonalities. Despite these similarities, its basic characteristics are novel and provide developing economies with new ideas on how to undertake development.
The first aspect of the model is perhaps the most central. It emphasizes the need to establish a relatively clean government apparatus that can effectively implement policy. Comparatively speaking, the Chinese government has all along been rather effective in policy implementation. With the anti-corruption campaign initiated by Xi Jinping in late 2012, the country has also witnessed what is likely to be the largest purge of corrupt practices and officials in history. This does not imply that the campaign is without problems, but it has had two basic effects: it has found approval from most Chinese citizens; and it has diminished the crassest and most abusive corrupt practices in the Chinese system.
The second characteristic of the model concerns efforts to establish integrated physical infrastructures and, more generally, great developmental pushes. China itself has started to lead several efforts in this regard abroad, especially via the Asian Infrastructure Development Bank (AIIB) and the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI). For many developing economies these initiatives de-emphasize market-opening reforms that can have unintended consequences, such as undermining national productive capacities. Rather, they favor physical infrastructure projects that can have direct benefits for national economies while enabling them to better participate in the global economy.
The third aspect continues to stress the central focus of Ramos' Beijing Consensus: pragmatic and eclectic economic policy approaches that incorporate a variety of methods. One of the less mentioned successes of the Chinese reform experience has been its experimental approach. Distinct sites for economic experimentation are set up, such as special economic, industrial, and trade zones. These enable lots of tinkering and bottom-up initiative to tease out reform solutions while controlling for unintended consequences.
This experimental approach is directly feeding into the fourth aspect of China's new development model. As Xi Jinping made clear during his speech at the 19th Communist Party Congress in October 2017, China aims to be at the forefront of technology innovation and environmental consciousness. Already the country is making great strides in the development of cutting-edge technologies, ranging from high-speed rail to electric vehicles and quantum communications. Much of this is occurring against the backdrop of unbridled private entrepreneurship that nonetheless benefits from government support. This combination of private initiative with massive state-guided investment stands in stark contradistinction to the tenets of the Washington Consensus. While it has to be adapted to local conditions, it has broad applicability across a range of development challenges.
The final aspect is also the newest. Chinese leaders have hitherto shied away from outlining a vision of development with global applicability. Ideological propositions during earlier reform era Party Congresses focused on China's own development challenges. This is changing.
At the 19th Party Congress, Xi Jinping outlined his thought on socialism with Chinese characteristics for a new era. Rather than emphasizing the development of GDP, corporations, or markets, the central focus rests on putting people at the centre of development, while creating harmony between humans and nature. Most significantly, this vision reaches beyond the Chinese people to promote “the building of a community with a shared future for mankind.”
Following the 19th Party Congress, the Chinese Communist Party hosted in early December 2017 a dialogue with world political parties. The document issued following this meeting was dubbed the “Beijing Initiative.” It directly builds on the 19th Congress' new guiding theory and holds that its innovative theoretical and practical outcomes do not only hold significance for China, but also provide good examples for the development of other countries, especially developing countries.
Putting forward a global vision is rather new for Chinese leaders. China's economic transformation is now allowing them to advance international initiatives, such as the BRI. As a result, China sees itself as taking on a global leadership role while formulating a new vision based on China's own development experiences.
Historically speaking, it is still too early to judge the global reception of these efforts. Nonetheless, certain aspects of the emergent China model are already being adopted by developing economies. Saudi Arabia, for example, has emerged as a rather unlikely candidate, but one whose recent initiatives clearly resemble the Chinese mold. “Vision 2030” aims to reduce the kingdom's dependence on oil, while diversifying its economy and making it into a leader in various industrial fields. Its remit is broad, encompassing not only economic initiatives, but also many social and cultural reforms. In fact, many of its development pushes have a resemblance to Chinese initiatives and fit in with Beijing's BRI infrastructure plan. Saudi Crown Prince Mohammad bin Salman has also launched a sweeping anti-corruption campaign with strong echoes of Xi's efforts to root out corruption in China.
“Vision 2030” received considerable criticism due to its overly ambitious goals. It is also not a wholesale adaptation of the Chinese experience, since the two countries face very different conditions. But it shows that the emergent China model is gaining international traction. Since the model has no coherent set of development principles as laid out in the Washington Consensus, its formulations remain conceptual and fluid. Perhaps this forms an inherent strength: its open-ended nature enables multiple interpretations on pathways to development. In fact, as the Washington Consensus fades, we are unlikely to witness a wholesale shift to a Chinese development dogma. Rather, the emergence of more varied views on what works and not in economic development could constitute the China model's greatest contribution.